Subtitles section Play video
Another contemporary economic myth is that we’re running out of resources. This fear
that we’ll use up the Earth’s natural resources has been with us pretty much since
the Industrial Revolution. Since the beginning of Industrialization, people have feared that
as firms used up the Earth’s resources that we would eventually run out of them. And this
fear continues today. However, this is largely a myth. In fact, we’re not running out of
resources. What we’re doing over time is learning to use resources more efficiently
and finding substitutes for resources as they do begin to deplete.
For example, consider the story of copper. In the early 1960s, telephone use in the United
States was expanding enormously. At the time, the only way to carry the data for telephones
was over copper wire. And so, as telephone use began to expand to new parts of the United
States, the demand for copper began to rise. As the demand for copper began to rise, so
did the price. The result of this is people began to worry we wouldn’t have enough copper
to wire the entire country for telephone use. But as we know, we managed to get around this
problem.
How did we get around it? Two things happened. First, as the price of copper went up, copper
producers found new sources of copper that were previously too expensive to explore.
More important, we saw the development of substitutes like fiber optic cable, which
is made out of sand. Now we carry our voice and data through fiber optic cable rather
than copper, conserving on the use of copper and providing us with more of the services
that copper was delivering.
Another example is oil. Ever since crude oil was first refined in the 19th century, people
have been concerned that we would eventually run out of oil. This became even more of a
concern in the 20th century with the development of the automobile and the increasing demand
for oil that came from that. But despite the concern that we might be running out, the
reality is that proven reserves keep growing year after year, even as people are concerned
that we’re running out.
If we look more closely at the data, what we find is that in 1882, estimates were that
only 95 million barrels of oil remained. Given that we were consuming oil at 25 million barrels
per year, that wasn’t going to last very long. But by 1919 oil was still with us, and
Scientific American reported only 20 years of oil left. Fast forward to 1950, over 30
years later, oil’s still with us and then the American Petroleum Institute estimated
100 billion barrels of oil left. Notice that’s 10 times the oil that was left in 1882. By
1956, people were predicting peak oil in the United States by 1970. But by 1980, remaining
proven oil reserves were at 648 billion barrels. By 1993, 13 years later, that had grown to
999 billion barrels. By the year 2000, it was over a trillion. And most recently in
2008, the best estimates are 1.2 trillion barrels of oil remaining.
When we put all this together what we discover is that we’re not really running out of
oil. As oil prices rise, what oil producers do is to begin to look for new sources of
oil. The reason why those proven reserves keep rising is because as the price goes up
it becomes profitable to search for oil in places that was previously too expensive.
So as a result, we end up finding oil that we didn’t know existed before the price
began to rise.
You can think about prices in the following way. Prices are an incentive wrapped in knowledge.
And so when the price of oil or copper rises, it does two things. It provides the knowledge
to producers that signals to them it’s time to find substitutes or it’s time to find
more efficient ways of using the good. But not just the knowledge, it also provides them
with an incentive to do so. At the higher price again, new sources of resources become
more profitable. As consumers balk at buying the good, substitutes become more profitable
as well.
So if we’re really concerned about running out of resources, the answer is not to restrict
our use of those resources, but to give the price system and competition in the market
economy the maximum play possible to create competitive prices and provide producers with
the knowledge and the incentive they need to economize and to find substitutes as resources
begin to get more scarce.