Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • In 1944, at the height of World War II, a British economist named Radford was serving

  • in the army. He was captured and lived in prison camps for more than a year. Prisoners

  • at the camps received Red Cross packages that contained food, cigarettes, and a few necessities.

  • These were precious supplies in POW camps. At first, prisoners gave away the things they

  • didn’t like, but before long they started trading instead. Radford’s explanation of

  • this behavior may surprise you. Very soon after capture people realized that it was

  • both undesirable and unnecessary in view of the limited size and the equality of supplies

  • to give away or to accept gifts of cigarettes or food.

  • Goodwill developed into trading as a more equitable means of maximizing individual satisfaction.”

  • More equitable? Really? Why would exchange be more equitable than gifts? Well, in a voluntary

  • exchange, both parties are better off, or they wouldn’t trade it all. Gifts are nice

  • but only the person receiving the gift is better off. Of course the giver might expect

  • a gift in return, but then, that’s exchange.

  • There are two reasons that this is important. Exchange corrects mistakes in allocation because

  • it moves stuff towards higher-valued uses. And exchange makes everyone who exchanges

  • a lot happier. There are two basic origins of exchange, and both are important.

  • First, same stuff different preferences. Let’s say we go on a field trip with boxed lunches

  • that each contain a sandwich, chips, pickle, and a cookie. I like chips and you like cookies.

  • I threw in my pickle to get you to agree, and we make the exchange. Were both happier

  • with our lunches even though were still dealing with the same amount of food overall.

  • Second, there’s same preferences, different stuff. Suppose I have apples and you have

  • oranges, but we both prefer eating fruit salad with the two mixed together. If we exchange,

  • then we can both have fruit salad. Were both happier with the same amount of fruit.

  • That’s remarkable.

  • In a world of scarce resources, each voluntary transaction means that people get happier

  • without any change to the total wealth that was available. That’s what makes trade so

  • powerful.

  • What if we have different stuff and different preferences? I do an exercise in class to

  • illustrate this. I give away T-shirts to my students, but I cheat. I make sure almost

  • every one of them ends up with the wrong size. So I ask, are you happy with your T-shirts?

  • Maybe 10 percent say that they are. Then I let them exchange shirts if they want to,

  • but only with their neighbors in the same row. Nonetheless, shirts move. You trade with

  • your neighbor, she trades with hers; the shirts travel around, improving the welfare of both

  • buyer and seller at every step. When it’s over, maybe 30 percent of the students are

  • happy with their shirt. It’s a big improvement but still not great.

  • Then I let people trade with anyone in the class. The class goes wild. Extra larges trade

  • for small, mediums for larges, and so on. It looks like chaos with people waving shirts,

  • calling out sizes. No plan, no direction, but at the end of trading, how many say theyre

  • happy? Ninety percent or more. The same number of shirts at the start, no one in charge,

  • and yet we went from 10 percent satisfied to 90 percent satisfied. Some of the shirts

  • changed hands many times. No one knew where the shirt was headedit just went. And everyone

  • who exchanged was happier. It seems like magic, but it’s just markets.

In 1944, at the height of World War II, a British economist named Radford was serving

Subtitles and vocabulary

Click the word to look it up Click the word to find further inforamtion about it

B1

我們為什麼要交換東西? (Why Do We Exchange Things?)

  • 134 10
    Ching Hung Lin posted on 2021/01/14
Video vocabulary