Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • >> Hello, everyone. Thank you for joining us today for our webinar on Behavior Economics

  • 101. My name is Michael Roush, and I'm the manager of financial empowerment and innovation

  • at the National Disability Institute. Today, I am joined by Wynne Lum, philanthropy manager

  • at Bank of America; Nicole Truog, associate director, the Center for Financial Security

  • at the University of Wisconsin Madison; and Anya Samak, who is the assistant professor

  • at the University of Wisconsin Madison. Before we get started with today's webinar, we do

  • have some housekeeping tips that we need to go over. My colleague, Nakia Matthews is going

  • to cover that information. >> Good afternoon, everybody. The audio for

  • today's webinar is being broadcast through your computer. Please make sure that your

  • speakers are turned up or your headphones are plugged in. You can control the audio

  • broadcast via the audio broadcast panel, which you see here below. If you accidentally close

  • the panel you can reopen it from the top menu item by going to communicate, join audio broadcast.

  • You can also use this to control the sound if the sound becomes distorted. If you do

  • not have sound capabilities on your computer or you prefer to listen by phone, you can

  • dial the number you see here. I will also put the information into the chat box. You

  • do not need to enter an attendee ID. Real-time captioning is provided during this webinar.

  • The captions can be found in the media viewer panel which appears in the lower right-hand

  • corner of the webinar platform. If you want to make the media viewer panel larger, you

  • can minimize some of the other panels like chat, Q&A or participant and conversely if

  • you do not want to see the media viewer panel, you can minimize it. There will be a question

  • and answer session at the end of the webinar. Please use the chat box or the Q&A box to

  • send any questions you may have to us during the course of the webinar. We will directly

  • -- direct these questions accordingly. If you are listening by phone and not logged

  • into the webinar platform, you may also submit questions by e-mailing them directly to me,

  • Nakia Matthews at nmatthews@ndi-inc.org. Please note that this webinar is being recorded and

  • that the materials will be put on the NDI website. If you experience any technical difficulties

  • during the webinar, please use the chat box to send me a message, Nakia Matthews. Or you

  • may e-mail me at nmatthews@ndi-inc.org. >> Great. Thank you, Nakia. Today's webinar

  • is our second in a three-part series that we are doing with support from Bank of America.

  • Our first webinar was introducing us to financial capabilities and key concepts and strategies

  • surrounding financial capability. Today's webinar is to introduce us to Behavior Economics.

  • What is it? What is the impact of Behavior Economics? Our guests today will help us understand

  • this topic. We are thankful for our friends from the University of Wisconsin, the Center

  • for Financial Security, for partnering with us today on this webinar. Please note that

  • today's webinar is not disability specific as we are exploring this topic together. And

  • then together we will ponder how Behavior Economics applies to the work that we are

  • doing together to advance the economic self-sufficiency for persons with disabilities. Our objective

  • for today's webinar are to define Behavior Economics, understand key components and look

  • at strategies to use as we work to create positive financial habits for clients we serve.

  • I would like to thank our sponsor of today's webinar, Bank of A merica, for their support

  • of expanding the financial capability of persons with disabilities. I would also like to thank

  • Bank of America for choosing the National Disability Institute to be one of the nonprofit

  • organizations highlighted on Bank of America's Times Square billboard this weekend and the

  • weekend of June 1st. If you are in the New York City area and can make it down to times

  • square, please do and take a picture in front of the billboard. When our logo comes up.

  • And send it to us. We'd love to highlight our partners with the Bank of America billboard

  • and NDI logo displayed and we're very honored for this opportunity and we thank Bank of

  • America for highlighting the National Disability Institute. For those of you that are new to

  • the National Disability Institute, before we turn it over to our presenters, I would

  • like to share with you a little bit of information. The National Disability Institute is a national

  • nonprofit organization dedicated to building a better economic future for Americans with

  • disabilities. We are the first national organization committed exclusively to championing economic

  • empowering -- empowerment, and financial stability for all persons across the full spectrum of

  • disabilities. National Disability Institute affect change through public education, training,

  • technical assistance, and policy development to help the one in three Americans with disabilities

  • living in poverty take steps towards brighter financial futures. To learn more about the

  • National Disability Institute, go to RealEconomicImpact.org. At this time, I would like to turn it over

  • to our friends at Bank of America. And we have Wynne Lum, who is the fanatical the -- the

  • philanthropy manager. Wynne, have you've been able to join us? -- have you've been able

  • to join u s? -- have you been able? Wynne will be joining us in just a minute. Until

  • he does join us, Nicole, can I turn it over to you?

  • >> Yes. Can you hear me okay? >> Perfect. Thanks, Nicole.

  • >> No problem. I'm delighted to participate today. I wanted to take a moment to say a

  • few words about the Center for Financial Security -- financial security. We are and applied

  • research Center and our research really focuses on working to build financial capabilities

  • for families and individuals over the life course. We do this through research that looks

  • at the measurement of financial capabilities, targeting interventions to populations at

  • risk, and also testing strategies and products and services. And so I couldn't leave you

  • today without a little plug for the center and have provided some resources here. I hope

  • you'll take a look at our website where we have a lot of our research published and also

  • policy briefs that are two to three page snapshots of our research. And all of our research,

  • we couldn't do it without our affiliates. And Anya is one of 50 plus affiliates who

  • are researchers across the country and across the campus working to look at financial capabilities.

  • If you're interested in learning more about financial security over the life course, we

  • do have an online conference coming up that's the pathways 2013 link. So thank you to Michael

  • and his team. I look forward to hearing more from Anya.

  • >> Great. Thank you, Nicole. And thank you for joining us today and for connecting us

  • with Anya. I think we might have Wynne back on the line, before we turn it over to our

  • main presenter, Wynne will be joining us momentarily. Nakia, I sent you the number. One piece I'd

  • like to share with you before Wynne joins us is that we have a partnership with Bank

  • of America's disability -- Disability Advocacy Network. And we are partnering with members

  • of the Bank of America team to increase awareness on financial wellness for persons with disabilities

  • through two opportunities. We have the financial education training as well as disability awareness

  • training for VITA volunteers, tax and asset building coalitions, debt management partners,

  • IDA and financial education providers. If you are interested in being connected with

  • a representative from Bank of America through the Disability Advocacy Network, please send

  • me an e-mail, Michael Roush, at mroush@ndi-inc.org. And we will be able to connect you to these

  • volunteer opportunities within your area. And so now what I'd like to do is I think

  • we have Wynne Lum on the l ine. So, Wynne, I'll turn it over to y ou.

  • >> Michael, thank you very much. Thank you for talking about the Disability Advocacy

  • Network at Bank of America. You mentioned earlier the admission -- the mission for the

  • National Disability Institute. Your mission is the reason why we are pleased to partner

  • with you and your organization, to help consumers be better able managing their finances. And

  • you had mentioned the times square recognition -- we were recognizing a handful of our have

  • -- partners and the wonderful work they do. Thank you for doing the work that you are

  • doing. This is a great time to be part of this conversation and this learning session

  • we're having. I'm in between frazzled -- so this is a great day you picked for this conversation.

  • When I mean I'm in between, we just finished with Mother's Day. And I was just stressed

  • out on what to get and the gifts I had to buy. And now were going from Mother's Day

  • to Father's Day to graduation, prom and everything else we have to do, not to mention necessities

  • that we all have. So how do you pay for all that? What used decide to get? What's going

  • to make mom and dad happy? What's going to make the graduate happy? And then do -- cannot

  • even afford to do it? I don't have to worry about affordability, do I? The marketers are

  • telling me that I can pay with easy pay, I can delay away, installment, I can pay with

  • other people's money. And so all of this is stressing me out because we all know that

  • impulsive buying can lead to some bad habits. And we need to be more thoughtful, we need

  • to be more deliberate, we need to be able to help ourselves manage our finances. That's

  • one of the reasons I'm interested in the work that the National Disability Institute is

  • doing but also the work that's being done by the University of Wisconsin Center for

  • financial security. They are some of the leading pioneers and experts and smart people doing

  • this work under the leadership of Dr. Michael Collins and Nicole Truog, who we're going

  • to hear from today, and Anya Samak in all the work they're doing to help us achieve

  • financial security. So we at Bank of America believe that consumers should be more thoughtful

  • and should be able to help themselves, because better consumers make better customers for

  • us but they also help relieve the stress so that we're not all frazzled with understanding

  • how to manage our finances. Michael, I'm interested in learning from the panelists today and what

  • they're doing. Thank you for letting us be a part of this.

  • >> Great. Thank you, Wynne. We appreciate you being on the call today. So now is the

  • main part of our webinar presentation today. And we're really excited to bring this topic

  • to you all. It's a topic that we've been exploring and looking at as we've traveled across the

  • country. Partners from both the asset building community, financial services as well as the

  • disability community have said to our team, what is Behavior Economics? What does it include?

  • Please bring us some information on it. And so when we reached out to the University of

  • Wisconsin, they connected us with Anya Samak, who is going to share some great information

  • with us today. She's been studying Behavior Economics. And we're delighted to have Dr.

  • Samak join us today. So with that, Anya, I'm going to turn it over to you.

  • >> Great. Hopefully everyone can hear me. >> Sounds great.

  • >> Yes? Good. My name is Anya Samak. I've been a professor at the University of Wisconsin

  • Madison and Center for Financial Security the past year. Before that, I was doing behavioral

  • economics research at the University of Chicago. And I received my PhD in experimental behavioral

  • economics from Purdue University. So I've been working on behavioral Econ for quite

  • a while and also mostly working on general behavioral principles that can be shared across

  • many domains. Not just thinking about why people choose to save versus spend or how

  • people to -- choose to allocate their money and what behavioral biases exist in that decision

  • but also very related topics such as, why do people choose to exercise or not? Why do

  • they choose to eat healthy or not? How do people decide about philanthropic giving and

  • so on? Today I'm going to be more general and you'll learn a little bit about the different

  • main principles in behavioral economics and how they can be applied to contact. So when

  • I talk today, I'm going to break the presentation up into three components. First, I'm going

  • to tell you what but it -- Haverhill economics is. As Michael said, behavioral Econ 101.

  • Then I'm going to tell you a little bit about how economists use experiments to study behavior.

  • Finally I'll give you some lessons on how insights from behavioral economics can be

  • applied in real settings and give you some examples of studies that have done this. So

  • before we get started I'm going to tell you about economics. When a lot of people think

  • about economics or if I meet someone at a party and tell them that I'm an economist,

  • people usually assume that when I'm interested in is studying money. How do people decide

  • to spend their money? What does the GDP look like? And that is macroeconomic q uestions.

  • Really, as economists, we think about any decision being an economic one, because microeconomics

  • is really the study of how individuals or firms make decisions to allocate limited resources.

  • Limited resources could be money but it also could be time. You could think about choosing

  • whether to buy a TV or invest that money in a retirement account as an economic decision.

  • You could also think about choosing whether to spend time watching TV or choosing to spend

  • that time exercising as an economic decision, because you're allocating limited resources.

  • As economists, we have two main components of a decision. The first component is the

  • a c onstraint. That tells us what the individual can do. It gives us the amount of money they

  • have to spend, gives us the hours in the day that are available to allocate across activities.

  • The second component is p references. That tells us what the individual wants to do.

  • In general, we assume that being jewel -- the individual's objective is to maximize satisfaction,

  • whether they receive satisfaction from activities or receive satisfaction from consumption g

  • oods. That in a nutshell how micro economists think about decision-making. So let's start,

  • what is behavioral economics? With one anecdote. Suppose we have George, whose choosing whether

  • to invest in a 401(k) plan at work. This slide tells you what we would typically believe

  • George would do. As economists, this is what we believe George will do. As policymakers,

  • we might also believe this is what he would do. We give George some information about

  • the 401(k). Give him that information under the assumption that he's going to carefully

  • consider all of the information that's given to him. And then he's going to use all this

  • information to maximize his satisfaction over his lifetime. Is going to know exactly what

  • he's getting into and he's going to think about how he feels today, how much money he

  • needs for consumption today, and how much money he will need for consumption at retirement.

  • We're also going to assume that George is doing this in a bubble. He's ignoring what

  • his friends are doing, ignoring what others are doing, he's focusing only on the information

  • that's given to him. Now, here's the behavioral Econ of what really happens. What really happens

  • is that George doesn't have time or processing capability to understand fully the information

  • that we give him. He may glance at some of the information that is given to him, but

  • he's not going to have the full information. Even if the full information is in front of

  • him, he's not going to be fully processing that information. Second, he is going to try

  • to maximize his satisfaction over his lifetime but then he might put it off until later or

  • he might not very easily anticipate his future satisfaction or understand what his future

  • self will need at r etirement. He's also not in a bubble when he's making this decision.

  • He does all this after checking what his friends are doing, what his colleagues are doing,

  • what's on TV and everything else around him is going to have an influence on his decision.

  • Moreover, because he's only glanced at his information, the information about what his

  • friends are doing might even be more of an influencing factor than if he had fully processed

  • that information. So this illustrates what I like to think of as the three principles

  • of bounded nets, that people are bounded in their ability to make their decisions -- principles

  • of boundedness. There are behavioral biases that prevent people doing what economists

  • believe is their objective, to maximize their overall lifetime satisfaction. The first one

  • is that George carefully considers all information. Likely, that doesn't really happen. What likely

  • happened is that George falls prey to what's called bounded rationality. Processing information

  • is costly from a time, effort perspective, and they can be common biases to how information

  • is received, so probability information is very difficult to process. Information that

  • is far in the future, difficult to comprehend and apply to your own situation now. The second

  • one is George maximizing satisfaction over his lifetime. What really happens is that

  • people have bounded willpower. That's another way of saying that they discount the future.

  • So they put off doing things they don't like to do, but they believe that they'll get to

  • it later. And finally, George ignoring what his friends are doing. In fact, we know that

  • people care about others. They make decisions with the impact of their behavior on others

  • in m ind. And they also use cues from the environment, especially cues from advisers,

  • to make those decisions. And these three principles are what we can think of as the psychological

  • underpinnings of behavioral economics. The behavioral economist take a lot insights from

  • the psychology field to try to understand what it is about the brain that causes these

  • biases. For bounded rationality we know that the brain is limited in its capacity to process

  • information. So we're not all calculators that can immediately process spreadsheet of

  • information. It takes a lot of time to process this information. When information is difficult

  • and complex, people often use rules of thumb. So one rule of thumb could be I'm just going

  • to look at the very first asset on that list of assets that I could contribute to and that's

  • the one I'm going to choose. These kinds of rules of thumb can lead to a few problems.

  • It can lead to overload of information if there's too much information, I may not make

  • a choice at all. It may lead me to incorrectly understand the probability of positive and

  • negative outcomes, especially for the financial a ssets. The next psychological underpinning

  • is bounded willpower. The bounded willpower is another way of saying time preferences.

  • People have different preferences for money today versus money in the future. People often

  • lack self-control. So as we were talking about impulsive buying, we may buy something today

  • if the consequences of that choice do not arrive until later in the future, for example

  • in a few months when the credit card bill is due. Bounded willpower makes it so we may

  • not be doing things that are good for us even though we know that those things are good

  • for us. Finally, bounded selfishness is the last psychological underpinning I want to

  • highlight. In general, people like to help others. They use cues from others to understand

  • the cost and benefits of different decisions and we fall prey to marketing as well. We

  • also care about people and their own groups succeeding. We may spend money on things that

  • help people in our in groups. So behavioral economics is economics but takes it a step further. We use concept

  • from psychology to investigate how social cognitive and emotional factors motivate decision-making.

  • Whereas before when we were just micro economists, we made simple assumptions like, George prefers

  • $100 to $50. $100 is most likely to give him a higher satisfaction than $50. But that might

  • not always be true. For example, people will prefer sometimes $50 to $100 if they can get

  • a $50 now but I have to wait a year to get the 100. People are impatient. The other one

  • that could happen is you could prefer 50 to 100 if getting 100 requires filling out a

  • form. That's why mail-in rebates tends to be so popular, people believe that they're

  • going to believe that they're going to fillable form, form, but they never get around to it.

  • Filling out the form is costly, it takes time and processing power to remember that the

  • form needs to be filled out. You prefer 50 to 100 unless getting 50 means that your financial

  • advisor is less well-off. So not only do we care about how people in our in group are

  • doing, our family and friends, we might also feel that -- feel bad about going against

  • a financial adviser's advice if that means that the advisor will be less well-off. The

  • next question is, why do we study behavior? We are interested in setting behavior for

  • a few reasons. The first, we're interested in describing what people actually do and

  • why they do it. Second and more importantly we want to recommend what individual route

  • to do. And what society ought to do. So what kinds of interventions or policies should

  • be in place to help individuals make better financial choices or make better health-related

  • choices and so on? In order to recommend i nterventions, we need something very important

  • which is cause and effect. In the example here, we believe that the Apple is the cause

  • which is causing the surgeon guy to fall backwards. But we need to be sure that it really is the

  • Apple that's having this effect before we can recommend that apples should not be allowed

  • at the hospital. Perhaps this guy just had a cold and was sneezing and the Apple happened

  • to hit him at the same time. We need to be very careful to disentangle the effects of

  • these two things because otherwise, we are -- removing the Apple would not have the effect

  • we expected. Studying cause and effect relationships can help us clearly point out which interventions

  • are going to cause certain behaviors to occur or not occur. And that brings us to my next

  • point, which is how do economists study behavior? When we study behavior, what we care about

  • most is the cause and effect question. I'm going to give an example of a case study on

  • financial education. We'll talk a little bit about what it means to try to disentangle

  • the causes and effects. So suppose that we are studying the ability of associates who

  • work at a firm to make better choices about how they manage their finances. Does -- to

  • that extent we as a -- advertise a new educational program, grow your wealth. And we invite 5000

  • qualified associates at the firm to join the program. 2000 of them are interested in learning

  • to save money. They decide to participate. We invite all 2000 to join. They all do very

  • well in the program. At the end of the study, we make the following comparison: we compare

  • the group who had participated, the 2000, with the group who hasn't participated, the

  • remaining 3000 we invited but did not join. We find that the 2000 have clearly done better.

  • They've saved more money, they've decreased their loans and so on. So the question is,

  • is the program a success? By most measures, it seems like it is. So what really happened?

  • Do one thing that happened is we had what economists call selection bias. The selection

  • bias caused our results to be overstated. So we have the guy on the left who joined

  • the program because he wanted to start saving money. He may have chosen to start saving

  • money anyway, but the program helped him. He's representing those 2000 who chose to

  • join the program. We have the guy on the right, who didn't join the program, because he didn't

  • care about saving money and he'd rather buy a flat-panel LCD T V. So this guy is very

  • different from the first guy. That is selection bias, the types of people who join the program

  • were very different from the types of people who didn't. And now we can't find a cause

  • and effect relationship. We don't know if it was the program or the types of people

  • who joined it who caused the effect, because we compared a bunch of people who are like

  • the guy who is watering his plants to the guy who is holding up the no sign. We know

  • for sure that the no guy is not going to be saving money, but we're not clear whether

  • the guy watering the plant would have saved money anyway or not. That causes us to overstate

  • our effect, because the guy who joined the program also has the m otivation, the intrinsic

  • motivation, to save from the beginning. The problem with this is then if we start recommending

  • the program to others, we often recommend it by saying that any person who joins the

  • program will be able to save. That's not entirely accurate, because we have no data on the guy

  • who didn't want to join the program and whether him joining the program would get into save

  • or not. So one way that economists try to get the cause and effect relationship is to

  • do what's called a randomized Field experiment or RCT, randomized control trial is what it's

  • called in medicine. The way we would go about this is slightly different. In the same scenario,

  • suppose we have 2000 people who chose to participate in the program. And these 2000 people were

  • located in five different cities. After the associates expressed their interest to participate,

  • we select the random subset, suppose we select cities A and B. Offer grow your wealth as

  • a pilot just to those programs. We then compare all those who wanted to participate in cities

  • A and B with those who wanted to participate but did not get the opportunity in C D and

  • E. What we've done there is remove the selection bias. So we know that it was the program and

  • not the people that caused the effect. I see we've got a question which is that we don't

  • know if anyone's income is sufficient to allow them to a save anything. It's a very good

  • question. And I'm using this just as I hypothetical example a program we could use. You could

  • imagine that the 2000 who chose to participate, if we compare the A and B guys to the other

  • guys, we should have the same proportion with different incomes in both groups. So we break

  • those people into two groups and we have what's called a control group and a treatment g roup.

  • We control who gets offered the intervention. The control group is the group for comparisons.

  • They wanted to participate but were not able to. The treatment group is the group of interest.

  • They wanted to participate and were able to. We expect that because we randomly put people

  • into groups. The same proportion of people with low income but both in treatment and

  • control. And the same proportion of people with high income in treatment and control.

  • So in that way, we could actually get people's income at baseline and we could compare across

  • to look at how the different levels of income are affected by the intervention. So that

  • was a good question. Now, the next question of course i s, what about the nonparticipants?

  • We've got these 2000 to participate -- 3000 didn't participate. Is there anything we can

  • do to try to figure out whether we can bring programs to these nonparticipants? We can't

  • force people to participate in a program. But we could use different behavioral interventions

  • to try to get them to join the program. One such example is going to be incentives. I'll

  • talk about that in a bit. So how would we get more participants in this study? We anticipate

  • that the guy who did not want to join the study may not want to join it for a few behavioral

  • reasons. One of those is going to be that the consequences of not saving money are far

  • in the future. He's not thinking about that right now. He would rather make a decision

  • to have a benefit now such as buying a TV or any other consumption good, and he wants

  • to save later. What we know from bounded willpower is that he may actually believe that he will

  • save later. So he believes that he is maximizing his satisfaction over his lifetime, but he

  • cares more about the present than the future. One way that we could incentivize this guy

  • to participate is to bring an incentive now to motivate behavior. Very good examples of

  • this would be if every time he put money into his savings account, he receives some kind

  • of coupon or voucher for recognition on the company website showing that he's a good participant

  • in the program. The other way to do it is to include a way for this guy to commit to

  • joining the program l ater. Perhaps he could commit to joining the program in six months

  • from now, which he's likely to do because he does believe that he will save money later,

  • he just doesn't have the willpower to save money today. Finally, we could use social

  • feedback, we could let him know about the social norms and about how many other people

  • have joined the program. And their success. Next, I'm going to talk about how insights

  • from behavioral economics can be applied. This is where I'm going to bring up some real

  • research examples. This guy on the left is pressing the help button. And the reason is

  • that we do think that people want to make choices that are optimal for them but the

  • problem and challenge is that they must overcome many behavioral biases. The ones we've discussed

  • today are bounded rationality, bounded willpower and bounded selfishness. These are problems

  • that people have that make it difficult, barriers for them to actually making the decision that's

  • going to be optimal for them. I'm going to talk about five different lessons of behavioral

  • interventions that can help to change behavior for the better. The first one I'll talk about

  • is the power of default. Then I'll talk about the cost of information. And then I'll talk

  • about incentives for today. I'll talk about demanding a commitment. And I'll talk about

  • some social strategies. And I'm not using just financial examples here, because what

  • we believe is that these behavioral principles can be shared across many domains including

  • financial decision-making, health-related decision-making, choosing to donate to a philanthropic

  • fund and so on. We'll start with the first one. About the power of default. In any decisions

  • that you could possibly make, your inaction in that decision triggers some default results.

  • So if you were at a company and you don't sign up for health insurance plan by the deadline

  • you are given, the default is no health insurance for the year. If you are at a company that

  • has an option for -- 401(k) plan, the default for not opting in to that plan is no 401(k)

  • plan. You do not sign up to be an organ donor, the default is typically you're not an organ

  • donor. What we know from behavioral economics is that if individuals put off difficult decisions

  • to the future, the default will be the most likely outcome. They procrastinate and procrastinate,

  • making the decision until finally the deadline has passed and then nudged into the default

  • state. Suppose that we change the default. We change no other policy accept to say, now

  • for the 401(k), the default is going to be automatic enrollment. If you don't touch the

  • paperwork, and you do nothing, you are automatically in the 401(k). If changing the default changes

  • behavior, we call this a nudge. We're not requiring people to join a 401(k). We're simply

  • changing the way you join. Now, rather than having to joined by doing paperwork, you have

  • to choose not to join by doing the same paperwork. The evidence that I have for lesson one comes

  • from a paper by David and co-authors from 2004. They conducted a field experiment with

  • an employer in which they changed over time the way that the 401(k) enrollment worked

  • -- by David Laibson. At first the employer had an opt in policy in which the worker can

  • select and then choose an amount to contribute. And then later, the employer had an opt out

  • policy with some default rate of 1% or 2% of the salary. The opt out case, the worker

  • was defaulted into accepting a 401(k) participation and the rate, or had to act to opt out. What

  • they found is that this change in default significantly increased enrollment. In fact,

  • when offered the default rate, many people were defaulted into that rate. If you look

  • at the small graph on the left, you see here the fraction of participants -- of employees

  • in the 401(k) plan, the Orange line shows the people hired during auto enrollment. The

  • amount is 80% of people who are enrolled in the 401(k) versus just 20% of people who are

  • hired before auto enrollment. Even after 48 months of tenure at the company we see that

  • the green lines below the Orange line showing that being hired at auto enrollment does not

  • cause people to opt out over time either. On the right, you can see here too the distribution

  • of contribution rates where the orange bars represent being hired during auto enrollment

  • with the default rate of 2%. Most people say that the default rate -- stayed at the default

  • rate of 2% regardless of their income. We might expect people with higher income to

  • choose higher contribution rates. And people with lower income to choose lower contribution

  • rates. That did not really happen in this particular study. The lesson here is that

  • default rates are particularly strong ways to get people to change their behavior. And

  • people don't even know that their behavior is being changed. They must be used carefully,

  • because even individuals with very low income who may not need to save in a 401(k) at all

  • and should instead be paying off their credit card debt are also being awful enrolled in

  • the 401(k). So this policy, which seems benign, actually caused a big behavior change. The

  • next lesson is that information has a cost. We always think about providing the consumer

  • with as much information as possible in order to make sure that his decision is more informed.

  • However, what we know from bounded rationality is that processing information is difficult

  • and individuals often rely on -- we can actually simplify information. Some of my work in the

  • financial literacy domain is on using graphical representation, which can be more effective

  • than textbased information to get people to understand financial concepts. More information

  • creates overload and is not always better. If you have too many, for example options,

  • you could cause worse outcomes by having people do more rules of thumb processing and more

  • processing of full information. The type of work that I do is actually called visual analytics.

  • So I use interactive visual tools that people can interact with to try to see things like

  • financial portfolio selection and risk diversification visually rather than just textually to try

  • to see how credit card debt will pile up in a visual form rather than just knowing that

  • APR for example. We find in lab experiments that visual analytics can improve confidence,

  • reduce decision time and actually result in higher quality choices when information sets

  • are complex. Lesson three is now incentives. So we know that bounded willpower makes it

  • difficult to see the benefits of an action that is good for you. Exercising and eating

  • well will improve my health in the long run. But I care about less -- care less about the

  • long run, more about the short run. If I have an incentive today to do something that's

  • good for me in the future, that actually changes my decision problem. It creates an immediate

  • benefit for my actions. Now I'm considering the cost and benefit of the action with the

  • benefit that I have in the present. Whether it's a couple dollars every time I go to the

  • gym, whether it is recognition from a friend that I did well, incentives in the present

  • are very important. The example I have here is a study that myself and my colleague, John

  • list, ran in the lunchroom. We actually see that over 40% of the content is thrown away

  • by kids. Which is a high rate of waste. We know kids are at the highest BMI ever and

  • nutrition education has had limited effectiveness and is costly. What we did in this study is

  • we looked at the effect of providing small gifts to children if they choose a healthy

  • food. We give them a choice of a cookie or fruit and told them they could only choose

  • one. And we randomly put different school lunch rooms in two different treatments. We

  • had a control group in which they just made a choice, a treatment group where they received

  • a small toy if they chose a fruit, and the small toys were on the line of $0.10 each

  • and we had a treatment group where they received some education and also made a choice, the

  • education was about a five minute message about the food period. This is the results

  • we have. Period one, which is before we did the intervention and two which is after. We

  • can see that in period one, about 20% of kids were choosing the fruit and 80% were choosing

  • c ookies. Cookies are the less healthy but higher benefit in the present choice. Now

  • we can see what happens when we introduce education. It actually had no significant

  • effect and almost a negative effect on the proportion of kids that are choosing the fruit.

  • Finally, what we find is a very powerful effect of incentives. The fruit choice increased

  • to 80% with only 20% choosing cookies when we introduced just a small toy. These are

  • three different incentive treatments that we ran. This type of radically effective incentive

  • has also been documented in other work including things like getting children to study for

  • their exams, getting adults to attend the gym regularly and so on. And is now being

  • tested for different types of financial interventions as well. Finally, we have commitment devices.

  • Individuals want to do better but the bounded willpower prevents them from doing better

  • in the present. So a commitment device is a way to assure that you follow through with

  • a plan. A good example of this is CDs or restrictions on withdrawals in the financial services.

  • Another good example is gym memberships. And finally if you see people putting their credit

  • cards in the freezer, that's a commitment not to take that credit card out even when

  • you have bounded willpower to do that. So there was a study by Dellavigna and Malmendier

  • in the last 10 years or so where they looked at analyzing data from gym m emberships. The

  • idea is that if people are maximizing their satisfaction, they should spend only as much

  • money as they need in order to go to the gym. What these researchers actually find is that

  • people pay more if they get a gym membership than if they pay per visit. And this is evidence

  • for the fact that people value commitment devices. If the average cost per visit is

  • $19 and the drop in rate is $10, the people paying $19 are the ones who have the annual

  • monthly membership. People are willing to pay up to $600 in this study for having this

  • commitment device to make them go to the gym. Finally, social strategies are very effective.

  • We can use social information and social cues to help people comply with desirable behaviors.

  • For example, financial coaching has been very effective, primarily because you are held

  • accountable to another person -- less so because of the financial information that they may

  • provide you. If you learn you're standing in a social group, so if you learn you are

  • being less environmentally friendly than others in your neighborhood, you may be more likely

  • to purchase environmentally friendly lightbulbs. That's a study that one of my colleagues has

  • done. Learning about what the social norms are helps people to conform to those norms

  • especially if those norms are things like weight loss and quitting programs, quitting

  • smoking. And receiving a signal based on what a role model is doing. Finally, tidying incentives,

  • the now incentives I talked about two group performance seems to have a big effect because

  • if I'm driving down the group, I feel more like I need to be proactive in making sure

  • that the group succeeds. Some evidence for this social strategy has been found in giving

  • to charities. Seed grants are really effective at getting others to donate. Social information

  • is very effective at getting people to donate to charity. Financial coaching, which I already

  • said, weight loss programs tend to be effective also because of the accountability component

  • and so on. And actually, that completes the discussion. We can open it up for questions.

  • >> This was -- thank you for the information. This was really valuable information. We do

  • have several questions. I would like to remind everyone that if you have additional questions,

  • you can go to the question and answer box on the lower right-hand corner of your screen

  • and ask the questions. So I will start reading off the questions. So far the majority of

  • these questions seems is going to you. Do you have examples or a resource that we can

  • go to, to share to provide insight on the graphical representations that you talked

  • about? >> Actually, yes. So I can send a link out

  • after the meeting. I have a book chapter on graphical representation but I don't have

  • that publicly available. I can put together some information on my website.

  • >> Okay. Great. We will definitely forward out your website to others. The next question

  • is, how do we choose the right incentives to offer for financial education or financial

  • coaching program? >> So that's a pretty broad question. I think

  • you'd want to try to understand better your population and who you're working with and

  • actually, I have many colleagues who study this question in particular, what's the right

  • incentive to use? Whether the incentives works just in the short term or whether their habit

  • formation effect in the long-term? We typically use randomized field experiments to try to

  • answer these questions, so we look at some possible incentives that we think may work

  • and then we randomize participants who receive incentives to study the value of each one.

  • If you did not have the ability to run a field experiment, you might want to think about

  • doing some surveys to learn about what incentives are sufficient for people to come. It's often

  • not going to be about monetary incentives. I think monetary incentives is the entire

  • transaction is viewed as a market transaction rather than intrinsically motivated transaction

  • so if I'm being paid to volunteer, that's very different from volunteering but if I'm

  • receiving a pen for volunteering, I may still feel I'm volunteering. Monetary incentives

  • can be explored more. >> Okay. Great. The next question that we

  • have here is, we have an idea a program, individual development account program. Every person

  • in the program has to use free tax preparation services. Should we offer an additional incentive

  • on top of this? [Indiscernible] placed on how many incentives possibly should we be giving to

  • an individual? Potentially, the free tax preparation services would be an incentive and hopefully

  • a behavior that they would keep afterwards, but should there be more than one incentive?

  • >> I think that would depend on the proportion of people that are using the service. If you

  • noticed that not many people are using the service, there may be a few barriers. So you

  • might want to think about if there's a barrier to calling to set up the appointment, maybe

  • you want to make it easier for them to get into the network and have reminders if someone

  • is calling them again and again to remind them to come i n. That can often be an effective

  • way to get people to show up, if they have more accountability. I think it's probably

  • -- if you are not finding the free tax preparation is a sufficient incentive, it's because they

  • don't receive the benefits right away. Do they receive their tax return right away after

  • they do the tax preparation? >> Right. So they would not.

  • >> Right. So it's possible that just that length of time is causing them not to choose

  • to follow through. I think with some low income populations especially, they have so many

  • other stressors on a day-to-day basis that for us, we might think of course, free tax

  • preparation is a great benefit. I'll fit it into my schedule for low income population,

  • might not even be on the radar until it's too late to receive that. So in that sense,

  • I think thinking about using a commitment device and reminder systems might work better

  • than an incentive and even an incentive as simple as a gift card they can use right away

  • might be helpful. >> Okay. Great. Lots of questions coming in

  • here. I know we only have five minutes left, but we might go a few minutes over if people

  • are willing to stay on just for a few more minutes because we have quite a few questions

  • coming in. Which is great. So I'm reading -- so can someone talk more about how people are

  • willing to pay for a commitment device? To make a, that question came from you. Do you

  • have anything else you can add to that question? >> No. That was all that I got.

  • >> Okay. Anya, are you able to answer that? >> In general, the reason I said people are

  • willing to pay for a commitment device is because of t he's time preferences have, which

  • is that we put off doing things that we don't like to do, to the future, but we believe

  • that in the future, we will do the things that we want to do. So having a commitment

  • device where I say I'm going to save but I'm going to save more tomorrow rather than today

  • can be an effective way to get people involved in saving without requiring them to save right

  • away. And similarly it can get people to start attending the gym without requiring them to

  • go right away, because coming in and doing a gym membership is less intimidating than

  • starting to go to the gym every single day. So what we find is that people want commitment

  • devices and they're willing to pay for them in the sense that they may be willing to take

  • a lower interest rate on a financial vehicle that in the long term they may have less liquidity

  • on Van higher interest rate on one where they have more liquidity. So if they recognize

  • that they have a problem with bounded willpower, they may be more likely to want to pay for

  • that commitment device to help themselves. On the other hand, we might not want people

  • to pay for the commitment device but get people to say.

  • >> Great. The next question is, is there one key strategy that your research highlights

  • as the most important in changing the behavior of individuals seeking to improve their financial

  • capability? >> I think that's an open question. What we've

  • really been trying to do is learn about whether it's incentives or social information or reminders

  • or all three of these things that are going to have the biggest impact at improving financial

  • behavior. >> All right. How do you know when a problem

  • is actually behavioral in nature? In many cases, problems that seem behavioral are actually

  • more structural. Do you have any guidance or baseline questions a program should ask

  • itself to understand this? >> Well, I think the structure of the program

  • may be what's causing the behavior that you observe. So if you have a program in which

  • it's very time costly for people to come in and register for it, requires a lot of paperwork,

  • there's not a lot of face to face interaction or social pressure to continue with the program,

  • then you would have behaviors that correspond to that, so people that are less likely to

  • join because of the barrier of taking a lot of paperwork, people who choose not to show

  • up if they're not reminded to come by someone else, that's a real person, and these sorts

  • of things. You really want to think about kind of, what are the behavioral barriers?

  • And look at the bounded willpower and bounded rationality especially to see if the way the

  • program is set up is causing people to act in line with those behavioral biases.

  • >> Great. What are some ways of helping individuals overcome the influence of family and friends

  • who don't have particularly good financial practices? So what are some of the ways in

  • helping individuals overcome the influence of others?

  • >> I think just -- I think that's really hard. We know very little about especially how behavior

  • is formed across the lifecycle. So when kids are younger and they learn from their parents

  • to behave in a certain way, how we can overcome those effects later in life -- those are all

  • open questions at this point. And you really want to think about whether we can have better

  • role models for people or whether we can incentivize them in some way to start forming new habits.

  • >> All right. Great. And do you have ideas for how to motivate financially stressed individuals

  • to enroll in a financial literacy class? I guess that kind of gets back to looking at

  • the best incentives. >> So we actually run a program in the South

  • side of Chicago, which is for financially stressed families but it's a parenting class.

  • And we offer incentives such as free child care for the children. And we also focus a

  • lot on peer to peer interactions. Having people in groups within the parenting class but essentially

  • having people in a group where once they arrive, there's three other people that are in their

  • group that they check in with and me knowing that you're going to be there and I'm choosing

  • not to come may be more likely for me to attend, so social pressure types of ways could be

  • useful. And accountability among the three people in that group. These types of things

  • have worked very well for weight watchers, for example, where you know that you have

  • to be accountable to others in your peer group but I think could also be effective for financial

  • literacy classes. >> All right. Great. Thank you. I know we've

  • come up to two minutes after 4:00. And there are several more questions that have come

  • in. And we have run out of time. So what I'd like to do with these additional questions

  • is I will send them over to the Center for Financial Security, to Anya and Nicole. And

  • to Bank of America. And we will answer these questions if that's okay with you, Anya. We

  • can send them to you and answer them and then we will attach this -- send the responses

  • out to everybody who registered for the webinar who participated today. So Anya, if you're

  • in agreement with that, we could go that direction. >> Yeah. That sounds great.

  • >> Excellent. Well, thank you. I would like to thank everybody for participating on today's

  • webinar and for asking these great questions. I think that this has been -- out of all the

  • webinars I've done, this has been one that we've had lots of questions and great feedback

  • -- so we really appreciate that. And please be sure to complete your evaluation and let

  • us know other topics you would like to explore or if you would like to explore this topic

  • even more, then we can host another webinar, possibly on this topic as well and going a

  • little bit deeper. For additional resources, please visit our website at www.RealEconomicImpact.org.

  • And also feel free to sign up for our listserv. There's information on your screen on how

  • to sign up for our listserv as well. A special thank you to Bank of America for their support

  • of this webinar series and really looking at how do we build the financial capabilities

  • of persons with disabilities? And understanding different terms and different topics that

  • we've heard about and really allowing us to ponder these thoughts and see how these apply

  • to persons with disabilities and really looking at how to build a better economic future.

  • A special thanks to Wynne Lum for his participation today as well. After the webinar, if you have

  • any additional questions, please feel free to contact me. My information is there, (727)278-1352

  • is my phone number and my e-mail address is on the website as well, mroush@ndi-inc.org.

  • I would like to thank Nicole Truog as well as Dr. Anya Samak, both with the University

  • of Wisconsin, for being good friends to the National Disability Institute and for providing

  • information with us today. Please note that our next webinar is June 12 at 3:00 p.m. And

  • this would be the third part of our series. It is on integrated service delivery. And

  • we will be hearing best practices of how organizations have brought various pieces when it comes

  • to financial literacy asset development and integrated them into their existing systems

  • and programs. So please be sure to join us for that webinar as well. Once again, all

  • questions, we will have been answered and sent out to everyone that has registered.

  • I'd like to thank my colleagues, Elizabeth Jennings as well as Nakia Matthews, for their

  • support of today's webinar. Thank you again for attending, and we look forward to talking

  • with you in June on our next webinar. Thank you.

  • >> [event concluded]

>> Hello, everyone. Thank you for joining us today for our webinar on Behavior Economics

Subtitles and vocabulary

Click the word to look it up Click the word to find further inforamtion about it