Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • Imagine as a thought experiment that you live in a small village

  • and depend on the local fish pond for food.

  • You share the pond with three other villagers.

  • The pond starts off with a dozen fish, and the fish reproduce.

  • For every two fish, there will be one baby added each night.

  • So, in order to maximize your supply of food,

  • how many fish should you catch each day?

  • Take a moment to think about it.

  • Assume baby fish grow to full size immediately

  • and that the pond begins at full capacity,

  • and ignore factors like the sex of the fish you catch.

  • The answer? One, and it's not just you.

  • The best way to maximize every villager's food supply

  • is for each fisherman to take just one fish each day.

  • Here's how the math works.

  • If each villager takes one fish, there will be eight fish left over night.

  • Each pair of fish produces one baby,

  • and the next day, the pond will be fully restocked with twelve fish.

  • If anyone takes more than one, the number of reproductive pairs drops,

  • and the population won't be able to bounce back.

  • Eventually, the fish in the lake will be gone,

  • leaving all four villagers to starve.

  • This fish pond is just one example of a classic problem

  • called the tragedy of the commons.

  • The phenomenon was first described in a pamphlet

  • by economist William Forster Lloyd in 1833

  • in a discussion of the overgrazing of cattle

  • on village common areas.

  • More than 100 years later, ecologist Garrett Hardin revived the concept

  • to describe what happens when many individuals

  • all share a limited resource,

  • like grazing land,

  • fishing areas,

  • living space,

  • even clean air.

  • Hardin argued that these situations pit short-term self-interest

  • against the common good,

  • and they end badly for everyone,

  • resulting in overgrazing,

  • overfishing,

  • overpopulation,

  • pollution,

  • and other social and environmental problems.

  • The key feature of a tragedy of the commons

  • is that it provides an opportunity for an individual to benefit him or herself

  • while spreading out any negative effects across the larger population.

  • To see what that means, let's revisit our fish pond.

  • Each individual fisherman is motivated

  • to take as many fish as he can for himself.

  • Meanwhile, any decline in fish reproduction

  • is shared by the entire village.

  • Anxious to avoid losing out to his neighbors,

  • a fisherman will conclude that it's in his best interest to take an extra fish,

  • or two,

  • or three.

  • Unfortunately, this is the same conclusion reached by the other fisherman,

  • and that's the tragedy.

  • Optimizing for the self in the short term isn't optimal for anyone in the long term.

  • That's a simplified example, but the tragedy of the commons

  • plays out in the more complex systems of real life, too.

  • The overuse of antibiotics has led to short-term gains in livestock production

  • and in treating common illnesses,

  • but it's also resulted in the evolution of antibiotic-resistant bacteria,

  • which threaten the entire population.

  • A coal-fired power plant produces cheap electricity for its customers

  • and profits for its owners.

  • These local benefits are helpful in the short term,

  • but pollution from mining and burning coal is spread across the entire atmosphere

  • and sticks around for thousands of years.

  • There are other examples, too.

  • Littering,

  • water shortages,

  • deforestation,

  • traffic jams,

  • even the purchase of bottled water.

  • But human civilization has proven it's capable of doing something remarkable.

  • We form social contracts,

  • we make communal agreements,

  • we elect governments,

  • and we pass laws.

  • All this to save our collective selves from our own individual impulses.

  • It isn't easy, and we certainly don't get it right nearly all of the time.

  • But humans at our best have shown that we can solve these problems

  • and we can continue to do so if we remember Hardin's lesson.

  • When the tragedy of the commons applies,

  • what's good for all of us is good for each of us.

Imagine as a thought experiment that you live in a small village

Subtitles and vocabulary

Click the word to look it up Click the word to find further inforamtion about it