Subtitles section Play video Print subtitles Hey! How ya doin' econ students? This Mr. Clifford. Welcome to ACDC econ. Right now we're going to talk about perfect competition. Because I know a few things Because I know a few things about being perfect. [Mumbles] stupid Alright before jumping to perfect competition let's take a step back and talk about the four market structures. Every product out there is produced in a market that's one of these for market structures there's perfect competition, monopolistic competition, oligopoly and monopoly. I'm going to explain perfect competition this video but the other market structure: imperfect competition is also super important. A great example of a product that is produced in perfect competition is oranges or strawberries or milk. No, NO, Paul, I'm not drinking another gallon of milk! You'll remember that firms inside perfect competition have several characteristics the most important one is that their products are completely identical as other firms, that means that they're perfect substitutes for each other. Think about, a dairy farmer can't taste milk and determine if that was his cow or some other cow that produced that milk. It's the same way with all other firms are in perfect competition another key characteristic is that there's many small firms and plenty of people producing this product. Now, if you put those together, you find out that these firms are: price takers. This means they have to take price that is set by the market. So, they have no control over the price. It'll make more sense if I show it to you in graphs. What we have right here is the market for milk. You learned this before, it's got demand and supply and it sets an equilibrium at ten dollars. so this is the industry graph, or the market graph, that includes all the different firms that produce milk. Right here is the graph for one individual firm Since their price takers, the demand for this firm is horizontal it is perfectly elastic. This is because they have no control over the price If they raise the price up, to 11, then no one is going to go to them, they will go to all the other dairy farmers and there's no reason for them to lower the price below 10, because people are going to buy as many units they sell, at ten dollars this horizontal demand curve is the demand, but is also equal to marginal revenue The marginal revenue is the additional revenue the firm gets when they sell another unit. So, if they sell another crate for ten dollars, their additional revenue is ten dollars They sell another crate, for another ten dollars, additional revenue is ten dollars. So, the demand equals the marginal revenue. It also equals the average revenue and the price. And your teacher will tell you that this is sometimes called Mr. DARP. (MR=D=AR=P) (Ehhhhhh) That's something I do my classes anytime I say the word MR=D=AR=P the students have to go: Ehhhhhhh This is the horizontal demand curve which equals the marginal revenue curve. Mr. DARP. (ehhhhhh) The point is, the demand and the marginal revenue are horizontal for the firm. Now, if we take some cost curves and put it on here, we can actually figure out how many units this firm should produce and we can calculate profits. Let's zoom in on the fim. Notice, we have a marginal cost curve and an ATC. The first question is to figure out how many units they should produce. That brings up the most important concept in all of microeconomics: Which is the profit maximizing rule. All firms should produce where MR equals MC. This is basically saying that you should always produce as long as the marginal revenue is greater than the marginal cost. At the point where the equal you should stop producing and that is the profit maximizing quantity. if you produce for the marginal cost is greater than marginal revenue, you make less profit than before. This firm is going to produce where MR hits MC, which is right there, at 10 units. they don't wanna stop at four units because they can still produce more profit And they don't want to produce eleven units because the additional cost is greater than the additional revenue of selling that unit. This is why you spent so much time learning about all the cost curves. You put them together with the rescue curves and now you can figure out how many units should a firm produce what is their total revenue, their total cost and how much is profit In this case, they're selling 10 units for ten dollars each. That big box, right there, is total revenue. Now, is that all profit? No, because some of it is cost. To calculate the total cost, you have to find the average total cost of each unit. Which is six dollars. 6 x 10 = 60 That box, in yellow, is the total cost. Total revenue of 100, minus 60 total cost gives you 40 dollars profit, green box This individual firm is maximizing profit we're at MR = MC and they're making economic profit of $40 or four dollars per unit. This graph is a firm in a perfectly competitive industry. and that's graph that you will have to draw and analyze do well on your tests. Make sure you feel comfortable drawing these side by side graphs; the market and the firm. with the firm showing profit or showing a loss or breaking-even in the long-run equilibrium. Another thing you should be able to do other than just draw the graph is use a chart to calculate how much profit is being made. You will learn how to do that in the next video. Hey, I hope this video helped you to understand perfect competition. If you like these videos, make sure to subscribe. Check out the next video that will explain the whole thing over again except using charts. Also, take a look at my microeconomics review video that covers all the concept of microeconomics. It'll get you ready for your final or for your AP tests. Alright, 'till next time.
B1 US revenue marginal firm profit competition cost Perfect Competition in the Short Run- Microeconomics 3.8 444 27 Harrison Mia posted on 2018/04/09 More Share Save Report Video vocabulary