Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • What do you remember about perfect competition?

  • I mean, how would you recognize a perfectly competitive industry if you ran across one?

  • In perfect competition, 1) there are a large number of sellers (there are a large number

  • of buyers too, but we won't be worrying about that just now).

  • No individual is large enough to affect the market.

  • 2) the product is homogeneous, or identical, or non-differentiated.

  • For example, milk.

  • When you go to buy 2% milk at the supermarket, what brand do you buy?

  • If you're like me, you buy whatever's on sale.

  • I have no brand loyalty whatsoever, because milk is milk.

  • 3) There's perfect information.

  • It's actually not enough for products to be identical; everyone has to know that the products

  • are identical.

  • Otherwise, we can be fooled by things like pretty packaging, or celebrity endorsements.

  • In a perfectly competitive industry, firm versus firm advertising is useless.

  • All you'd be doing is driving up your own costs, and then customers would just buy from

  • a cheaper competitor.

  • However, you may see industry-wide advertising, like a “Got milk?”

  • campaign, “pork, the other white meat,” orbeef -- it's what's for dinner.”

  • These kinds of campaigns raise demand for each firm's product across the industry.

  • 4) Easy entry and exit.

  • Because firms can enter and exit the industry at will, long-term profits would be affected,

  • but we'll get to that in just a bit.

  • For the individual firm owner, the combined effect of these characteristics is that he/she

  • has no power to control price, and will earn zero economic profit in the long run.

  • Let me ask you this: If the individual firm cannot set the price, then where does the

  • price come from?

  • Think back to our market activity earlier in the semester: in a market with lots of

  • buyers and sellers, the price is determined collectively by the market supply and market

  • demand.

  • This, then, is the prevailing price for each firm.

  • What happens if the firm doesn't like this price?

  • If it tries to charge more than P*, all of the customers will go someplace else.

  • So, the firm would be forced back down to P*.

  • If it tries to charge less than P*, then all customers in the industry will come to this

  • firm.

  • Sounds good, right?

  • Wrong.

  • This firm cannot accommodate the entire industry demand -- costs would skyrocket, and the firm

  • would be forced back up to P* to get rid of some of the customers.

  • All of this means that the firm is a price taker, forced to accept P*, the market-determined

  • equilibrium price.

  • Note that this also means, because the firm charges P* regardless of the quantity demanded,

  • that P* represents the firm's demand, as well.

  • Remember that perfectly elastic demand curve from earlier this semester, where consumers

  • are so hypersensitive to price that price is all that matters?

  • Well that's this market structure.

  • OK, so -- you're producer in a perfectly competitive market, and you have no control

  • over the price that you can charge.

  • Is there anything you do have control over, that you can make decisions about?

  • A perfectly competitive firm may not be able to choose its price, but it can choose how

  • much output to produce.

  • The firm owner will choose the level of output that will maximize his/her profits (see episode

  • 26B to see why marginal revenue equals marginal cost will always be the profit maximizing

  • rule).

  • Soyou're a firm owner in a perfectly competitive industry, you can't choose the

  • price that you charge, but you can select the amount of output that you produce.

  • In order to maximize profit, you will always choose the level of output were marginal revenue

  • equals marginal cost.

  • Take a look at the perfectly competitive firm and see where this occurs.

  • Hmmm

  • I need to choose output such that marginal revenue equals marginal cost, but right now

  • I don't see marginal revenue OR marginal cost!

  • Let's start with marginal revenue.

  • Marginal revenue is the additional revenue that you earn when you sell an additional

  • unit of output.

  • For a perfectly competitive firm, since all units are sold for the same price, each unit

  • sold always adds the same amount of revenue, P*.

  • For example, if price is $5, then the total revenue for zero units is $0, for one unit

  • is $5, for two units is $10, and so on.

  • Selling one more unit generates five additional dollars of revenue each time.

  • Therefore marginal revenue is equal to the equilibrium price.

  • Note that this is only true for perfect competition.

  • What about marginal cost?

  • Well, marginal cost is actually pretty easy -- we constructed the cost curves, marginal

  • cost included, before knowing anything about market structures.

  • Those cost curves in the same regardless of the structure we're operating in.

  • This means that the marginal cost for the perfectly competitive firm is justmarginal

  • cost (remember that J-shaped, Nike-swish thing), and now all we need to do is select the level

  • of output were marginal revenue equals marginal cost.

  • Now, because there are no average cost curves in this diagram yet, I can't actually show

  • you how large or small the profits are; only that q* will be the best level of output for

  • this particular producer, based on the profit-maximizing rule.

  • Let's look at just one example of how to find profit using this model, then we'll do more

  • cases in class.

  • What if my perfectly competitive producer is operating in an industry where price is

  • greater than the cost per unit?

  • I can already tell that this producer will be making profits, since there's more coming

  • in for each unit than there is being paid out in cost, but let's see what it looks like.

  • Notice that I positioned the average cost curves below the price line.

  • Where is MR = MC?

  • This gives me q*.

  • At q*, what is the total revenue coming in?

  • Revenue is the price I can charge times the number of units that I sell.

  • In this case, the green area.

  • At q*, what's the total cost of producing this output?

  • It's the cost per unit, ATC, times the number of units I sell -- in this case the red area.

  • The amount of revenue (in green) that doesn't get chewed up by the costs (in red) is profit.

  • In this case, I've indicated profit by the blue area.

  • In the short run, this producer earns positive profits.

  • Why do I sayin the short run”?

  • Because those short run profits attract the sharks -- other outside firms see the profits

  • and enter the industry to set up shop.

  • This causes industry supply increase, driving the price downward.

  • In the end, the entry only stops when there are no more profits to attract the sharks;

  • until price is equal to average total cost, and the firms just break even.

  • In the long run, a perfectly competitive firm's profits are always equal to zero.

  • NEXT TIME: Monopoly TRANSCRIPT00(MICRO) EPISODE 26: PERFECT COMPETITION

What do you remember about perfect competition?

Subtitles and vocabulary

Click the word to look it up Click the word to find further inforamtion about it